Выбрать главу

Growth failure has been particularly noticeable in Latin America and Africa, where neo-liberal programmes were implemented more thoroughly than in Asia. In the 1960s and the 1970s, per capita income in Latin America was growing at 3.1% per year, slightly faster than the developing country average. Brazil, especially, was growing almost as fast as the East Asian ‘miracle’ economies. Since the 1980s, however, when the continent embraced neo-liberalism, Latin America has been growing at less than one-third of the rate of the ‘bad old days’. Even if we discount the 1980s as a decade of adjustment and take it out of the equation, per capita income in the region during the 1990s grew at basically half the rate of the ‘bad old days’ (3.1% vs 1.7%). Between 2000 and 2005, the region has done even worse; it virtually stood still, with per capita income growing at only 0.6% per year.[21] As for Africa, its per capita income grew relatively slowly even in the 1960s and the 1970s (1–2% a year). But since the 1980s, the region has seen a fall in living standards. This record is a damning indictment of the neo-liberal orthodoxy, because most of the African economies have been practically run by the IMF and the World Bank over the past quarter of a century.

The poor growth record of neo-liberal globalization since the 1980s is particularly embarrassing. Accelerating growth – if necessary at the cost of increasing inequality and possibly some increase in poverty – was the proclaimed goal of neo-liberal reform. We have been repeatedly told that we first have to ‘create more wealth’ before we can distribute it more widely and that neo-liberalism was the way to do that. As a result of neo-liberal policies, income inequality has increased in most countries as predicted, but growth has actually slowed down significantly.[22]

Moreover, economic instability has markedly increased during the period of neo-liberal dominance. The world, especially the developing world, has seen more frequent and larger-scale financial crises since the 1980s. In other words, neo-liberal globalization has failed to deliver on all fronts of economic life – growth, equality and stability. Despite this, we are constantly told how neo-liberal globalization has brought unprecedented benefits.

The distortion of facts in the official history of globalization is also evident at country level. Contrary to what the orthodoxy would have us believe, virtually all the successful developing countries since the Second World War initially succeeded through nationalistic policies, using protection, subsidies and other forms of government intervention.

I have already discussed the case of my native Korea in some detail in the Prologue, but other ‘miracle’ economies of East Asia have also succeeded through a strategic approach to integration with the global economy. Taiwan used a strategy that is very similar to that of Korea, although it used state-owned enterprises more extensively while being somewhat friendlier to foreign investors than Korea was. Singapore has had free trade and relied heavily on foreign investment, but, even so, it does not conform in other respects to the neo-liberal ideal. Though it welcomed foreign investors, it used considerable subsidies in order to attract transnational corporations in industries it considered strategic, especially in the form of government investment in infrastructure and education targeted at particular industries. Moreover, it has one of the largest state-owned enterprise sectors in the world, including the Housing Development Board, which supplies 85% of all housing (almost all land is owned by the government).

Hong Kong is the exception that proves the rule. It became rich despite having free trade and a laissez-faire industrial policy. But it never was an independent state (not even a city state like Singapore) but a city within a bigger entity. Until 1997, it was a British colony used as a platform for Britain’s trading and financial interests in Asia. Today, it is the financial centre of the Chinese economy. These facts made it less necessary for Hong Kong to have an independent industrial base, although, even so, it was producing twice as much manufacturing output per capita as that of Korea until the mid-1980s, when it started its full absorption into China. But even Hong Kong was not a total free market economy. Most importantly, all land was owned by the government in order to control the housing situation.

The more recent economic success stories of China, and increasingly India, are also examples that show the importance of strategic, rather than unconditional, integration with the global economy based on a nationalistic vision. Like the US in the mid-19th century, or Japan and Korea in the mid-20th century, China used high tariffs to build up its industrial base. Right up to the 1990s, China’s average tariff was over 30%. Admittedly, it has been more welcoming to foreign investment than Japan or Korea were. But it still imposed foreign ownership ceilings and local contents requirements (the requirements that the foreign firms buy at least a certain proportion of their inputs from local suppliers).

India’s recent economic success is often attributed by the pro-globalizers to its trade and financial liberalization in the early 1990s. As some recent research reveals, however, India’s growth acceleration really began in the 1980s, discrediting the simple ‘greater openness accelerates growth’ story.[23] Moreover, even after the early 1990s trade liberalization, India’s average manufacturing tariffs remained at above 30% (it is still 25% today). India’s protectionism before the 1990s was certainly over-done in some sectors. But this is not to say that India would have been even more successful had it adopted free trade at independence in 1947. India has also imposed severe restrictions on foreign direct investment – entry restrictions, ownership restrictions and various performance requirements (e.g., local contents requirements).

The one country that seems to have succeeded in the postwar globalization period by using the neo-liberal strategy is Chile. Indeed, Chile adopted the strategy before anyone else, including the US and Britain, following the coup d’état by General Augusto Pinochet back in 1973. Since then, Chile has grown quite well – although nowhere nearly as fast as the East Asian ‘miracle’ economies.[24] And the country has been constantly cited as a neo-liberal success story. Its good growth performance is undeniable. But even Chile’s story is more complex than the orthodoxy suggests.

Chile’s early experiment with neo-liberalism, led by the so-called Chicago Boys (a group of Chilean economists trained at the University of Chicago, one of the centres of neo-liberal economics), was a disaster. It ended in a terrible financial crash in 1982, which had to be resolved by the nationalization of the whole banking sector. Thanks to this crash, the country recovered the pre-Pinochet level of income only in the late 1980s.[25] It was only when Chile’s neo-liberalism got more pragmatic after the crash that the country started doing well. For example, the government provided exporters with a lot of help in overseas marketing and R&D.[26] It also used capital controls in the 1990s to successfully reduce the inflow of short-term speculative funds, although its recent free trade agreement with the US has forced it to promise never to use them again.More importantly, there is a lot of doubt about the sustainability of Chile’s development. Over the past three decades, the country has lost a lot of manufacturing industries and become excessively dependent on natural-resources-based exports. Not having the technological capabilities to move into higher-productivity activities, Chile faces a clear limit to the level of prosperity it can attain in the long run.

вернуться

21

M. Weisbrot, D. Baker and D. Rosnick (2005), ‘The Scorecard on Development: 25 Years of Diminished Progress’, September 2005, Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR), Washington, DC, downloadable from http://www.cepr.net/publications/development_2005_09.pdf

вернуться

22

Some commentators argue that recent advance in globalization has made the world more equal. This result is highly disputed, but, even if it were true, it has happened because, to put it crudely, a lot of Chinese have become richer, not because income distribution has become more equal within countries. Whatever happened to ‘global’ inequality, there is little dispute that income inequality has increased in most countries, including China itself, over the past 20–25 years. On this debate, see A. Cornia (2003), ‘Globalisation and the Distribution of Income between and within Countries’ in H-J. Chang (ed.), Rethinking Development Economics (Anthem Press, London) and B. Milanovic (2005), Worlds Apart – Measuring International and Global Inequality (Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford).

вернуться

23

For example, see D. Rodrik and A. Subramaniam (2004), ‘From “Hindu Growth” to Growth Acceleration: The Mystery of Indian Growth Transition’, mimeo., Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, March 2004. Downloadable from http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/IndiapaperdraftMarch2.pdf

вернуться

24

Annual per capita GDP growth rate between 1975 and 2003 was 4% in Chile, 4.9% in Singapore and 6.1% in Korea. See UNDP (2005), Human Development Report 2005 (United Nations Development Program, New York).

вернуться

25

Chile’s per capita income (in 1990 dollars, as all the following figures are) was $5, 293 in 1970, when Salvador Allende, the left-wing president who was subsequently deposed by Pinochet, came to power. Despite the bad press Allende has been getting in the official history of capitalism, per capita income in Chile rose quite a lot during his presidency – it was $5, 663 in 1971 and $5, 492 in 1972.After the coup, Chile’s per capita income fell, hitting the bottom at $4, 323 in 1975. From 1976, it started rising again and peaked at $5, 956 in 1981, mainly thanks to the financial bubble. Following the financial crash, it fell back to $4, 898 in 1983 and recovered the pre-coup level only in 1987, at $5, 590. The data are from Maddison (2003), Table 4c.

вернуться

26

Public Citizen’s Global Trade Watch (2006), ‘The Uses of Chile: How Politics Trumped Truth in the Neo-liberal Revision of Chile’s Development’, Discussion Paper, September 2006. Downloadable at http://www.citizen.org/documents/chilealternatives.pdf.