Выбрать главу

There was a reduction in protection in the 1846 tariff law, although the average ad valorem duty on the 51 most important categories of imported goods was still 27 per cent. There was a further reduction in 1857, made possible by the coalition of the Democrats, the cloth manufacturers who wanted raw wool placed on the ‘free list’, and railroad interests who wanted tariff-free iron from abroad. Bairoch describes the . . , period between 1846 and 1861 as one of ‘modest protectionism’.[69] However, this protectionism is only ‘modest’ by the historical standards of the USA (see table 2.1). It must also be pointed out that, given the high transportation costs of the period, which prevailed at least until the 1870s, US tariffs would have been a greater barrier to international trade than the European ones, even if both had been at the same level.[70]

However, the tension surrounding both the tariff and slave issues persisted between North and South, and finally culminated in the Civil War (1861-5). The Civil War is commonly thought to have been fought solely over the issue of slavery, but in fact tariffs were another important issue. Garraty and Carnes state that ‘raj war against slavery would not have been supported by a majority of Northerners. Slavery was the root case of secession but not of the North’s determination to resist secession, which resulted from the people’s commitment to the union’.[71] Given that the South had seen tariffs as the major existing liability of the union while the abolition of slavery was still only a theoretical possibility, the importance of the tariff issue in causing the secession cannot be over-emphasized.

Lincoln’s victory in the presidential election of 1860 would have been very difficult, if not impossible, had the leading protectionist states of Pennsylvania and New Jersey not switched their allegiance to the Republican Party thanks to its election pledge to maintain increased protection.[72] The pledge (the ‘twelfth plank’ of the platform) was deliberately worded ambiguously in such a way as to assuage the free-trade element in the Party.[73] At the same time, it was still acceptable to the protectionist states, given that Lincoln was a ‘true blue protectionist’ and thus seen as someone who would live up to the spirit of the pledge, once elected.[74]

Early in his political career Lincoln had been a leading member of the hard-line protectionist Whig party and an enthusiastic follower of the charismatic politician, Henry Clay. Clay advocated the ‘American System’, .which consisted of infant industry protection (‘Protection for Home Industries’) and infra structural development (‘Internal Improvements’), in explicit opposition to the ‘British System’ of free trade, and Lincoln fully shared his view.[75] Although during the campaign Lincoln was compelled to keep quiet on most of the controversial issues, including tariffs, in order to hold a diverse and young party together[76], he unwaveringly gave assurance of his protectionist belief when it was deemed necessary.[77]

Although he was consistently anti-slavery, Lincoln had never before advocated forceful abolition of slavery; he considered blacks racially inferior, and was against black suffrage. Given this, there was probably less to fear for the South on the slavery front than on the tariff front upon his election. Indeed, even in the early days of the Civil War, Lincoln made it clear that he was quite willing to allow slavery in the Southern states in order to keep the Union together. He enacted slave emancipation in the autumn of 1862 as a strategic move to win the war rather than out of moral conviction.[78]

In 1862, a new tariff act was introduced. It was disguised as ‘compensation’ for the increased excise tax and the emergency income tax during the Civil War, in order that the previous margin of protection could be maintained. This raised the rates to ‘their highest level in thirty years – much higher, in many cases, than the new excise taxes warranted’[79] In 1864, tariffs were raised still further, to their highest ever rates, to meet the demands of war expenditure; they remained at those levels after the war, although other internal taxes were repealed.[80] In this way, the victory of the North in the Civil War ensured that the USA remained the most ardent practitioner of infant industry protection until the First World War, and even until the Second World War – with the notable exception of Russia in the early twentieth century (see Table 2.1).[81]

In 1913, following the previous Democratic electoral victory, the Underwood Tariff bill was passed, leading to ‘a large increase in the categories of goods allowed free entry and to a substantial drop in average import duties’;[82] this reduced the average tariff on manufactured goods from 44 per cent to 25 per cent. However, the onset of the First World War made this bill ineffective and a new emergency tariff legislation was put in place by 1922, following the Republican return to power in 1921. In the 1922 law, although the tariffs did not return to their high 1861-1913 levels, the percentage effectively paid on manufactured imports rose by 30 per cent.[83]

Following the start of the Great Depression there came the 1930 Smoot-Hawley tariff – ‘the most visible and dramatic act of anti-trade folly’, according to Bhagwati.[84] However, this characterization is very misleading. While the Smoot-Hawley tariff provoked an international tariff war, thanks to its bad timing – especially given the new status of the USA as the world’s largest creditor nation following the First World War – it did not constitute a radical departure from the country’s traditional trade policy stance.[85]

In fact, the Smoot-Hawley tariff only marginally increased the degree of protectionism in the US economy. As we can see from table 2.1, the average tariff rate for manufactured goods that resulted from this bill was 48 per cent, which still falls within the range of the average rates that had prevailed in the USA since the Civil War, albeit in the upper region of this range. It is only in relation to the brief ‘Liberal’ interlude of 1913-29 that the 1930 tariff bill can be interpreted as increasing protectionism, although even then it was not by very much. Table 2.1 shows that the average rate of tariff on manufactures in 1925 was 37 per cent and rose to 48 per cent in 1931.

It was only after the Second World War that the USA – with its industrial supremacy unchallenged – finally liberalized its trade and started championing the cause of free trade. However, it should be noted that the USA never practised free trade to the same degree as Britain did during its free-trade period (1860 to 1932). It never had a zero-tariff regime like that of the UK, and it was much more aggressive in using ‘hidden’ protectionist measures. These included: VERs (voluntary export restraints); quotas on textile and clothing (through the Multi-Fibre Agreement); protection and subsidies for agriculture (compare this with the repeal of the Corn Laws in Britain); and unilateral trade sanctions (especially through the use of anti-dumping duties).[86]

In contrast to the attitude of a generation ago, represented by the above-mentioned work of North, there is now a growing recognition of the importance of protectionism among US economic historians, who used to be extremely wary of saying anything positive about it. Today, there seems at least to be a consensus that tariff protection was critical in the development of certain key industries, such as the textile industry in the early nineteenth century and the iron and steel industries in the second half of the nineteenth century.[87] Although some commentators doubt whether the overall national welfare effect of protectionism was positive, the US growth records during the protectionist period make this scepticism look overly cautious, if not downright biased.

вернуться

69

Garraty and Carnes, p. 335; Bairoch 1993, pp. 34-5; Luthin 1994, p. 611.

вернуться

70

Although a regular transatlantic steam service was inaugurated in 1838, steamships only came to replace sailboats as the major means of sea transportation in the 1870s (O’Rourke and Williamson 1999, pp. 33-4).

вернуться

71

Garraty and Carnes 2000, p. 405.

вернуться

72

Luthin 1944, pp. 614-24. It should be remembered that, as a coalition between the protectionst Whigs and the western Democrats who wanted free distribution of public land but in general wanted free trade, the Republican party in its early days was not an openly protectionist party.

вернуться

73

The plank read ‘[t]hat, while providing revenue for the support of the general government by duties upon imports, sound policy requires such an adjustment of these imports as to encourage the development of the industrial interests of the country; and we commend that policy of national exchanges, which secures to the working man liberal wages, to agriculture remunerative prices, to mechanics and manufacturers an adequate reward for their skill, labor, and enterprise, and to the nation commercial prosperity and independence’ (cited in Borit 1966, p. 309).

вернуться

74

Luthin 1944, pp. 617-18; Borit 1966, pp. 302, 309-31. One eyewitness records: ‘The Pennsylvania and New Jersey delegations were terrific in their applause over the tariff resolution, and their hilarity was contagious, finally pervading the whole vast auditorium’. Another wrote: ‘The scene this evening upon the reading of the ‘Protection to Home Industries’ plank in the platform was beyond precedent. One thousand tongues yelled, ten thousand hats, caps and handkerchiefs waving with the wildest fervor. Frantic jubilation’. Both are cited in Luthin 1944, p. 617.

вернуться

75

Luthin 1944, pp. 610-11; Fraysse 1986, pp. 99-100. One of Lincoln’s economic advisors was the famous protectionist economist Henry Carey (see below). Lincoln even appointed a close associate of Carey to a post in the Treasury in charge of tariffs, although Carey is known to have been frustrated by Lincoln’s unwillingness to take things as far as he wanted (Luthin 1944, pp. 627-9). Carey is reported to have said: ‘Protection made Mr. Lincoln president. Protection has given him all the success he’ has achieved, yet has he never, so far as I can recollect, bestowed upon her a single word of thanks. When he and she part company, he will go to the wall’ (his letter to Noah Swayne, enclosed as a copy in Swayne to Carey, February 4th, 1865, Carey Papers, Box 78; cited in Luthin 1944, p. 629).

вернуться

76

The Republican Party was only formed in 1856 out of an alliance between Northern manufacturing interests and small farmers of the West.

вернуться

77

Luthin 1944, pp. 624-5; Borit 1966, pp. 310-12.

вернуться

78

Garraty and Carnes 2000, pp. 391-2, 414-15; Foner 1998, p. 92. In response to a newspaper editorial urging immediate slave emancipation, Lincoln wrote: ‘If I could save the Union without freeing any slave, I would do it; and if I could save it by freeing all the slaves, I would do it; and if I could do it by freeing some and leaving others alone, I would also do that’ (Garraty and Carnes 2000, p. 405).

вернуться

79

Cochran and Miller 1942, p. 106.

вернуться

80

However, the increase was considered so exceedingly high that even Congressman Justin Morrill, one of the architects of the 1862 Tariff Act, is reported to have commented in 1870 that ‘lilt is a mistake of the friends of a sound tariff to insist on the extreme rates imposed during the war’ (originally cited in F Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States, Putnam, 1903; as cited in Cochran and Miller 1942, p. 106).

вернуться

81

And at least for the earlier period, we cannot underestimate the natural protection accorded to the US manufacturing producers by the sheer distance from Europe, given high transportation costs (Bairoch 1993, p. 35).

вернуться

82

Bairoch 1993, p. 37.

вернуться

83

Bairoch 1993, pp. 37-8.

вернуться

84

Bhagwati 1985, p. 22, n. 10.

вернуться

85

Kindleberger 1990a, pp. 136-7.

вернуться

86

I would like to thank Irfan ul Haque for raising this point.

вернуться

87

Lipsey 2000, pp. 726-7.