Выбрать главу

Source: Maddison 1995. The 1750 figures are extrapolated from 1820 data, with annual growth rate taken as 0.4 per cent for both the UK and France. 0.4 per cent is the weighted average of estimates by economic historians of England (de Vries 1984). It is widely accepted among economic historians that the French growth rate at the time was similar to that of England (Crouzet 1967).

Chapter 4

Lessons for the Present

4.1. Introduction

The discussion so far shows how the policies and institutions used by now-developed countries in the early stages of their development differ significantly from those that have commonly assumed to have been used by them, and even more from the guidelines recommended to, or rather more frequently demanded of, today’s developing countries.

In the next two sections of this chapter, I summarize the principal conclusions of chapters 2 and 3, and discuss whether we can really conclude that the current push for ‘good policies’ and ‘good governance’ by the developed countries amounts in fact to ‘kicking away the ladder’. Section 4.4 then considers some possible objections to my argument, while the final section draws some conclusions, and suggests new directions of research that have emerged from the present study.

4.2 Rethinking Economic Policies for Development

In Chapter 2, I looked at the policies that had been used by the now-developed countries (NDCs) during their development, from fourteenth century England down to the East Asian NICs in the late twentieth century.

My discussion confirms to a remarkable extent the observation made by List 150 years ago – a time when many would have laughed at the suggestion that, within two generations, Germany would be economically challenging Britain or that the USA would become the world’s leading industrial power. A consistent pattern emerges, in which all the catching-up economies use activist industrial, trade and technology (ITT) policies – but not simply tariff protection, as I have repeatedly pointed out – to promote economic development, as had been the case since before List’s time. The policy tools involved in such promotional efforts may have become more varied, complex and effective since List’s time, but the general pattern has remained remarkably true to type.

Whatever the exact policy method used, there seems to be a number of common principles that run through the lengthy series of successful development strategists starting from Edward III in the fourteenth century, through to Robert Walpole, Frederick the Great and Alexander Hamilton in the eighteenth century, to the nineteenth century US, German, or Swedish policy-makers, right down to their twentieth century East Asian or French counterparts.

As has been repeatedly observed over the last few centuries, the common problem faced by all catch-up economies is that the shift to higher-value-added activities, which constitutes the key to the process of economic development, does not happen ‘naturally’.[1] This is because, for a variety of reasons, there exist discrepancies between social and individual returns to investments in the high-value-added activities, or infant industries, in the catch-up economies.[2]

Given such discrepancies, it becomes necessary to establish some mechanisms to socialize the risk involved in such investments. Contrary to the popular view, this does not have to involve direct policy intervention such as tariff protection or subsidies, but could be done by establishing institutions which can socialize the risk involved in such projects (more on this later – see section 4.3). However, the institutional solution has significant limitations. First of all, institutions are by nature embodiments of general rules, and therefore may not be effective in addressing problems related to particular industries. Second, establishing new institutions can take a long time, as we argued in Chapter 3, and this is therefore likely to limit the ability of countries to respond quickly to new challenges. As a result, a more focused and quick-footed policy intervention may in many cases be preferable to institutional solutions.

However, the fact that direct state intervention, especially in the form of ITT policies, is often necessary for socializing the risks involved in the development of infant industries, does not mean that there is only one way of doing it – that is to say, by means of tariff protection.[3] As my discussion in Chapter 2 shows, there were many different policy tools used for the purpose across different countries, as a result of the differences in their relative technological backwardness, international conditions, human resource availability and so on. Needless to say, even within the same country the focus of promotion can – indeed has to – evolve over time with changing domestic and international conditions. Typically, the successful countries have been those that were able skilfully to adapt their policy focus to changing conditions.

вернуться

1

Of course, what these higher-value-added activities are will depend on the country and the period concerned. So, to take an extreme example, the manufacturing of wool cloth, which was the high-value-added activity of fourteenth and fifteenth-century Europe, is now one of the low-value-added activities. Moreover, high-value-added activities need not even be ‘(manufacturing) industries’ in the conventional sense, as is implied by the term ‘infant industry promotion’. Depending on where technological advances are happening, the high-value-added activities could be some of those that are officially classified as ‘services’.

вернуться

2

See Chang 1994, chapter 3; Stiglitz 1996; Lall 1998, for reasons why there may be such discrepancies. Very often, the problem is that the private sector entrepreneurs, whose cost-benefit profiles the state should be trying to influence, are missing altogether. This is, for example, the reason that Frederick the Great had to use (successfully) a small number of bureaucrat-entrepreneurs to develop his industries in Silesia or that many developing countries have had to use (in many cases unsuccessfully) public enterprises following their independence after the Second World War.

вернуться

3

Shafaeddin points out that List also regarded tariffs and subsidies as only two of many policies for industrial development (2000, pp. 9-10).