Выбрать главу

Moreover, the free-trade regime did not last long. By the 1880s, some hard-pressed British manufacturers were asking for protection. By the early twentieth century, reintroduction of protectionism was one of the hottest issues in British politics, as the country was rapidly losing its manufacturing advantage to the USA and Germany: testimony to this was the influence of the Tariff Reform League, formed in 1903 under the leadership of the charismatic politician Joseph Chamberlain.[50] The era of free trade ended when Britain finally acknowledged that it had lost its manufacturing eminence and re-introduced tariffs on a large scale in 1932.,[51]

2.2.2. USA

As List pointed out (see Chapter 1), Britain was the first country successfully to launch an infant industry promotion strategy. However, its most ardent user was probably the USA – the eminent economic historian Paul Bairoch once called it ‘the mother country and bastion of modern protectionism’.[52]

This fact is rarely acknowledged in the modern literature, however, especially that coming out of the USA, and even many otherwise knowledgeable people do not seem to be aware of it. No less an economic historian than Clive Trebilcock, an authority on European Industrial Revolution, when commenting on the introduction of 1879 tariffs in Germany, stated that tariffs were going up all over the world, including ‘even free-trade America’.[53]

Even when the existence of high tariffs is acknowledged, their importance is severely downplayed. For example, in what was until recently the standard overview of US economic history, North mentions tariffs once, only to dismiss them as an insignificant factor in explaining US industrial development. He argues, without bothering to establish the case and by citing only one highly-biased secondary source (the classic study by F’Taussig, 1892), ‘while tariffs became increasingly protective in the years after the Civil War, it is doubtful if they were very influential in affecting seriously the spread of manufacturing’.[54]

However, a more careful and unbiased reading of the history reveals that the importance of infant industry protection in US development cannot be overemphasized. From the early days of colonization in what later became the USA, protection of domestic industry was a controversial policy issue. To begin with, Britain did not want to industrialize the colonies and duly implemented policies to that effect (see section 2.3. for further details). Around the time of independence, Southern agrarian interests opposed any protection, while Northern manufacturing interests – represented by, among others, Alexander Hamilton, the first Secretary of the Treasury of the USA (1789-95) – wanted it.[55]

Indeed, many point out that it was Alexander Hamilton, in his Reports of the Secretary of the Treasury on the Subject of Manufactures (1791), and not Friedrich List as is often thought, who first systematically set out the infant industry argument.[56] In fact, as Henderson and Reinert point out, List started out as a free trade advocate and only converted to the infant industry argument following his period of exile in the USA (1825-30). While he was there, he was exposed to the works of Alexander Hamilton and the then leading US economist and strong advocate of infant industry protection, Daniel Raymond.[57]

In his Reports, Hamilton argued that competition from abroad and ‘forces of habit’ would mean that new industries that could soon become internationally competitive (‘infant industries’)[58] would not be started in the USA, unless their initial losses were guaranteed by government aid. This aid, he said, could take the form of import duties or, in rare cases, prohibition of import.[59] It is interesting to note that there is a close resemblance between this view and that espoused by Walpole (see section 2.2.1) – a point that was not lost on the contemporary Americans, especially Hamilton’s political opponents.[60] In turn, it should also be noted that both the Walpole an and the Hamiltonian views are remarkably similar to the view that lies behind East Asia’s postwar industrial policy (see section 2.2.7.).

Initially, the USA did not have a federal-level tariff system, and an attempt to grant the Congress tariff power in 1781 failed.[61] When it acquired the power to tax, the Congress passed a liberal tariff act (1789), imposing a five per cent flat rate tariff on all imports, with some exceptions, such as hemp, glass, and nails. Many tariffs were increased in 1792, although they still fell far short of Hamilton’s recommendations, which called for an extensive system of infant industry protection and subsidies. After that, until the war with Britain in 1812, the average tariff level remained around 12.5 per cent, but in order to meet the increased wartime expenses, all tariffs were doubled in 1812.[62]

A significant shift in policy occurred in 1816, when, as List noted (Chapter 1), a new law was introduced to keep the tariff level close to that from wartime as a result of the considerable political influence of the infant industries that had grown up under the ‘natural’ protection accorded by the war with Britain. This was done despite the fact that the revenue was no longer needed – especially protected were cotton, woollen, and iron goods.[63] In the 1816 tariff law, almost all manufactured goods were subject to tariffs of around 35 per cent.[64] Table 2.1 shows that the average tariff level for manufacturing products in the USA in 1820 was around 40 per cent. Initially, this measure was welcomed by everyone, including the Southern states, which hoped that it would help industries to grow in their territories. However, the Southern states soon turned against it because of their interests in importing superior quality British manufactures and because of the failure of the industries to emerge in their own territories.[65]

The Southern agrarian interests, with the help of the New England (and especially New York) shippers, were able to defeat bills calling for higher tariffs in 1820, 1821 and 1823.[66] However, in 1824, a new, still higher, tariff was enacted. In 1828 the so-called Tariff of Abominations further divided the country. This was because this time the northern and western agricultural interests were adding high tariffs on the raw materials or low value-added manufactures that they produced (e.g., wool, hemp, flax, fur and liquor), thus creating tension with the New England manufacturing states.[67]

Yet another tariff law was passed in 1832. This offered a 40 per cent tariff rate on average for manufactured goods – a much lower cut than the Southerners had wanted – and particularly high protection was accorded to iron and textile goods (e.g., 40—45 per cent on woollen manufactured goods and 50 per cent for clothing). This led to the so-called Nullification Crisis, started by South Carolina’s refusal to accept the law. A compromise bill was passed in 1833, which offered few immediate reductions but made a provision for gradual reduction over the next ten years, down to about 25 per cent for manufactured goods and 20 per cent for all goods. However, as soon as this ten-year reduction ended in 1842, a new tariff act was passed, raising duties back up to about the 1832 levels.[68]

вернуться

50

See Clarke 1999, on the rise and fall of the Tariff Reform League and Chamberlain’s role in it.

вернуться

51

Bairoch 1993, pp. 27-8.

вернуться

52

Bairoch 1993, p. 30.

вернуться

53

Trebilcock 1981, p. 83.

вернуться

54

North 1965, p. 694.

вернуться

55

Of course, there is no simple one-to-one correspondence between someone’s ‘material’ position and his/her intellectual position. Despite being a Southern slave-owner, Jefferson was strongly in favour of infant industry protection. In contrast, despite being from the Northern manufacturing part of the country and being a famous industrial inventor, Benjamin Franklin was not a supporter of infant industry protection. However, Franklin still supported protection of American manufacturing industry on the ground that the American industry would never be able to compete with European industry that could get away with paying subsistence wage, whereas the American industry could not, given the abundance of land and shortage of labour. See Kaplan (1931, pp. 17-27).

вернуться

56

Corden 1974, chapter 8; Freeman 1989; Reinert 1996. Of course, there were thinkers before Hamilton who had elements of the infant industry argument in their writings. For these, see Reinert 1995. According to Bairoch 1993, between Hamilton’s Reports and List’s National System of Political Economy, there were other writings advocating infant industry protection by authors such as the German Adam Muller and the Frenchmen Jean-Antoine Chaptal and Charles Dupin (p. 17).

вернуться

57

Henderson 1983; Reinert 1998. For further details on List’s life and work, see Henderson 1983. List’s full argument was published in The National System of Political Economy in 1841. However, according to Spiegel (1971), the earliest version of his argument for the development of national ‘productive power’ was made in a book that he wrote for the Pennsylvania protectionists in 1827, Outlines of American Political Economy (pp. 362-3).

вернуться

58

Bairoch (1993, p. 17) credits Hamilton for inventing the term, ‘infant industry’.

вернуться

59

Dorfman and Tugwell 1960, pp. 31-2; Conkin 1980, pp. 176-7.

вернуться

60

According to Elkins and McKitrick, ‘[a]s the Hamiltonian progress revealed itself - a sizeable· funded debt, a powerful national bank, excises, nationally subsidized manufactures, and eventually even a standing army – the Walpolean point was too obvious to miss. It was in resistance to this, and everything it seemed to imply that the ‘Jeffersonian persuasion’ was erected’ (1993, p. 19).

вернуться

61

Garraty and Carnes 2000, pp. 139-40.

вернуться

62

Garraty and Carnes 2000, pp. 153-5, 210; Bairoch 1993, p. 33.

вернуться

63

Garraty and Carnes, 2000, p. 210; Cochran and Miller, 1942, pp. 15-16.

вернуться

64

Bairoch 1993, p. 33.

вернуться

65

Garraty and Carnes 2000, p. 210.

вернуться

66

Cochran and Miller 1942, p. 16.

вернуться

67

Garraty and Carnes, pp. 219, 221.

вернуться

68

Bairoch 1993, p. 34; Garraty and Carnes 2000, pp. 262-3, 328; Cochran and Miller 1942, p. 18.